unionsnswinfo

CLEAN ENERGY INVESTMENTS FOR NEW YORK STATE: An Economic Framework for Promoting Climate Stabilization and Expanding Good Job Opportunities

By Robert Pollin, Heidi Garrett-Peltier, and Jeannette Wicks-Lim

This study examines the benefits of large-scale green energy investments for New York
State. It also proposes a policy framework for supporting such investments throughout
the state.
Large-scale clean energy investments throughout New York State can advance two fundamental goals:
1. Promoting global climate stabilization by reducing carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions and
other greenhouse gas emissions.
2. Expanding good job opportunities throughout the state.
solar panels.jpg
Reducing CO2 Emissions
The specific aim for clean energy investments will be to achieve, by 2030, a 50 percent
reduction below the 1990 level in all human-caused carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions in
New York State.
This translates into a CO2 emissions level of 100 million tons by 2030.
Current emissions are at 170 million tons. The emissions reduction by 2030 therefore
will need to be 40 percent relative to current levels.
CO2 emissions will fall due to reduced consumption of oil, coal and natural gas in
the state. The cuts in natural gas consumption will also support major reductions in
methane emissions.

Major Areas of Clean Energy Investments
 Energy Efficiency. Dramatically improving energy efficiency standards in New York’s
stock of buildings, automobiles and public transportation systems, and industrial production
processes.
Clean Renewable Energy. Dramatically expanding the supply of clean renewable
energy sources—primarily wind, solar, and geothermal power—available at competitive
prices to all sectors of New York State’s economy.

Job Creation through Clean Energy Investments
Making the large-scale investments in clean energy projects capable of achieving the 50
percent emissions reduction target by 2030 will generate between 145,000 and 160,000
jobs per year in the state.
New job opportunities will be created in a wide range of areas, including construction,
sales, management, electrical assembly, engineering, and office support.

Advertisements

INQUIRIES, INQUIRIES, INQUIRIES

 (Written 2015) by Neale Towart Job creation and maintenance were central until neoclassical training in the academy took over in the bureaucracy, to our detriment.

Economics… has always been partly a vehicle for the ruling ideology of each period (Joan Robinson)

manduck

The Productivity Commission (PC) is as misnamed as its predecessor, which was, officially, the Industries Assistance Commission. In reality it was the Industries Assassination Commission, and was certainly true to that name. The Victorian Liberal Premer, Rupert Hamer, is usually credited as the person who bestowed the Assassination moniker. The PC has unions in its sights. The history and the ideology of the Commission under various names show us what we are in for.

To understand where it is coming from we need to look at economic history. Before you nod off, remember that Australia as a nation for a continent was born of the tensions between free trade (SYDNEY) and protection of industry (MELBOURNE), and it helps to keep those broadly opposed ideas in mind. Federal governments between 1901 and 1987 generally kept a pragmatic “balance” between these views. Federation itself was only achieved when these conflicts were bashed into a shape acceptable to the various states.

TARIFFS

That job destroying and wage lowering body was itself a follow on from the Tariff Board, instituted in 1922. The Tariff Board was established as a stand-alone, seemingly separate from government departments. Tariffs could not protect us from the international depression of the late 1920s, and the economic policies needed to extract us from the mire did not flow, despite urgent calls from JM Keynes and Australian economists Copeland and Giblin, with Queenslander Red Ted Theodore the leading politician for the Keynesian approach. The war induced growth in expenditure did the job.

The need for population growth, a self-reliance ethos, state development of infrastructure, industry protection, price support and rural assistance schemes were the backbone of Australian economic development until the early 1970s. This is not to say these policies were uncontested, but the Australian economy did grow, ensured high pay rates and growing standards of living for all (white) citizens until the 1970s.

POST WAR RECONSTRUCTION: JOB SECURITY WAS KING

The policy drivers in the Federal sphere from the mid- 1940s had initially come from the Department of Post War Reconstruction with bureaucrats such as Nugget Coombs and Lyndhurst Giblin under the Curtin and Chifley governments, and under Menzies. Giblin pointed out, in 1943, that “the demand for job security was so strong and so general that no government could withstand it; full employment had become a ‘test of democracy.’ (Stuart Macintyre: Australia’s Boldest Experiment: war and reconstruction in the 1940s. Newsouth, 2015)
In 1963-5 the Vernon report expressed an alternative to the Treasury and Tariff Board approach, a reflection of the balance of political economic power. Although still a Liberal Country Party government, the membership of trade unions was above 50% and the acceptance of full employment was seen as political necessary. Classical economics was prepared to state that full employment was an unhealthy situation for the governance of capitalism. The Polish economist, Michael Kalecki (I hasten to add that Kalecki was fiercely opposed to this idea) had summed this up:
” … the assumption that a Government will maintain full employment in a capitalist economy if it knows how to do it is fallacious. In this connection the misgivings of big business about maintenance of full employment by Government spending are of paramount importance.” misgivings of big business about maintenance of full employment by Government spending are of paramount importance.”

NEO-CLASSICAL TRAINING IN THE ACADEMY

Evan Jones traces the increasing power grab to the increased role of university educated economists in Treasury, as against the accountants who had dominated until then.  As Joan Robinson, the British economist saw it “economic doctrines always come to us as propaganda. This is bound up with the very nature of the subject and to pretend that it is not so in the name of ‘pure science’ is a very unscientific refusal to accept the facts.”

The Department of Trade and Industry was opposed to Treasury, and was prepared to accept facts. It was supportive of the Vernon approach, which actually looked at how active economic policy framing did work or not in many countries, including shock horror, non-Anglo ones. They tried to look at and understand world markets something the Treasury officials would not do as they looked at their careful on-paper modelling.

The beginning of the end for this pragmatism came from Country Party leader Black Jack McEwens’ decision to appoint Alf Rattigan as head of the Tariff Board. McEwen was seen as the person responsible for the balance of tariffs and rural assistance. His appointment of Rattigan was a disaster

The Industries Assistance (Assassination) Commission (IAC) replaced the Tariff Board, with Rattigan still in charge. It first reported in 1973-4. It has been downhill from there.

One of the most infamous the Whitlam governments early decision was an across the board tariff cut of 25%. Evan Jones notes example of the devastation this brought on in the textile industry in towns in northern Victoria. Wangaratta Woollen Mills (the town’s second-largest employer) laid off 100 workers in early June. The smaller plants of the Cleckheaton firm also retrenched workers at Benalla (28, one shift) and Shepparton (17).Bruck (Aust), Wangaratta’s largest employer, then retrenched 40 workers, and didn’t replace 20 others who had resigned. Clark Fashions closed down at Benalla, retrenching 40 workers.”

THE JACKSON REPORT

At about this time, but too little too late, the Jackson report arrived, with the extraordinary sight of radical economist Ted Wheelwright on the committee. Ted’s approach to economics is summed up by Joan Robinson’s dictum that “The purpose of studying economics is not to acquire a set of ready-made answers to economic questions, but to learn how to avoid being deceived by economists. “ (Chapter 7, Marx, Marshall and Keynes, p. 75)

The report (not actual government policy) itself noted that “Market forces and tariff policy are not sufficient to achieve the desired industry structure. Positive policies are needed to develop particular industries.”

The oil crisis and world-wide economic recession saw the ALP move from the acceptance of Rattigan’s approach to a need to shore up the rising social dislocation. The ongoing crisis was used by Fraser as a reason to rein in the IAC, accepting the need to weigh social dislocation when arguing about tariff cuts. Pragmatism remained but the ground was shifting. The Jackson report was part of the economic argument that moving to a rigid neoclassical mainstream away from any vestiges of Keynesianism.

CRAWFORD

The Crawford report followed in 1977. Crawford had been a part of the Vernon Committee in the early 1960s but the report introduced us to the term “structural adjustment’” a code for the horrors to come. The IAC was partly held in check by the pragmatism of stability, but the boffins remained firmly in their silos and warded off any change that might threaten their neo-classical ideas.

HAWKE AND KEATING

The various IAC reports under Fraser had been put carefully to one side as they tried to ride out the storms. The early days of Hawke Keating saw a similar process, with the Accord acting as a brake on the wicked unionists demanding their fair share whilst industries “adjusted”.

The IAC was under review and was supposed to be more concerned with social and economic dislocation. It kept itself in the forefront of policy advice, despite opposition from a newish Bureau of Industry Economics (BIE), the Australian Manufacturing Council (AMC) and the Economic Planning Advisory Council (EPAC).

However the IAC, supposedly being pushed into a new culture, did not accept ideas of “picking winners” and the outcomes of industry reviews in the 1980s-90s shows how their approach remained unaltered, no matter what.

For example, the rapid decline of the heavy engineering sector in the 1980s was addressed by real industry planning and assistance policy.  Despite the massive job losses that were addressed by alternative policies the IAC reported that it was “crucial that industry restructuring take place as far as possible in response to market signals and are not distorted by government intervention.”

KEATING FOR THE MARKET

By 1991 Keating had made the Industry Commission the successor to the IAC. It used its models in reports on the finance industry (where it went along with deregulation orthodoxy) and under Costello in a report on rural Australia which saw the continued wilful neglect. The rigidity of their economic argument hardened.

ALTERNATIVES

Other approaches were advocated. Whilst not a strictly economic/industry policy report, the Coombs report on Australian government administration was about a massive restructure in public service, with a socio-economic approach based in Coombs long-term views on the role of government providing  a full employment economy.

Fraser looked for ways to get advice from outside the Treasury/IAC nexus to when he set up the BIE and the Department of Finance. Hawke and Keating created the AMC and EPAC with the same idea.  However the reports remained constrained by what Chomsky and Herman might call the “limits of the expressible”. That even this limited alternative advice was not welcome was shown by Opposition leader Hewson threatening to abolish the BIE in 1992.

 

aust reconstructed

The Trade Department even set up a Business- Union Consultation Unit in 1984. The Trade Development Council came from this, and saw its light briefly shine with Australia Reconstructed, a plan to remake Australian manufacturing based on successful ideas and practices elsewhere, with union involvement. By 1987, when the report was published, the tide was flowing out.

BEACHED

Trade was subsumed by Foreign Affairs, and central authority for economic planning was drawn back to Treasury. By 1991 trade wasn’t even a cabinet portfolio. Keating, the Treasury boffins best ever friend, instituted the National Competition Policy in 1992. Alternative sources of advice had largely been sidelined, abolished and ignored.

Howard, in 1998, drew the BIE and EPAC into the Industry Commission and it was all over. The three bodies became our current much beloved Productivity Commission and it is the only source of advice. There is no onus on them to consider social issues. Its right to inquire seems open ended.

PC and You and Me

The annual “report card” the PC does on industry assistance reflects this view. As Roy Green amongst others says the modelling the PC uses “has the effect of maximising the costs of government assistance and minimising its benefits.”

We can rely on the current inquiry into the workplace relations framework to reflect this and can be pretty certain that the “costs” of regulation (ie union involvement in getting and maintaining decent pay and conditions) will be seen as cost maximising and no attempt to calculate the massive benefits to Australian workers and employers will be attempted.

 

The Cashless Debit Card Evaluation: does it really prove success?

Janet Hunt has earlier reviewed the so-called reviewers of the cashless card and found them wanting. She has continued her scrutiny and shows the many failings of the supposedly successful trial that is now being extended.

“The Minister for Human Services, Alan Tudge, claimed the trial a huge success, and the Prime Minister was in Western Australia on 3 September, saying with great
conviction:
“It’s seen a massive reduction in alcohol abuse, in drug abuse, in domestic violence, in violence generally; a really huge improvement in the quality of life, not just for the families who are using the Cashless Welfare Card, but for the whole community.
But above all, above all it’s an investment in the future of the children.

Someone needs to tell them that the report does not say that. Indeed, the authors qualify a number of their apparently positive findings with various caveats, but, at the same time, the evaluation itself has serious flaws, so even these findings are contestable. Despite this, the trials are continuing, and new rollouts of the Cashless
Debit Card are proposed elsewhere.

New Zealand: Inequality in Wages and Self-Employment 1998-2015

In this report for the New Zealand Council of Trade Unions : Te Kauae Kaimahi  Bill Rosenberg shows rising inequality in the hourly rates of gross earnings (before tax and benefits) among both wage and salary earners and the self-employed over the period 1998-2015.

For wage and salary earners (employees) this study finds increasing inequality in average hourly wages. The exception is the lowest income decile which is heavily influenced by the minimum wage, whose income has risen on average at about the same rate as the top decile and rose faster during the Labour-led Government in the early 2000s than in previous or subsequent National-led Governments. Other than that, wage rates for the next 50 percent (deciles 2 to 6) of employees rose much more slowly than the wage rates of higher income wage and salary earners: the real average hourly wage of the top 10 percent rose by 39 percent while the low and middle income 50 percent rose by 18-20 percent between 1998 and 2015 in real terms.

Beyond Full Employment: What Argentina’s Plan Jefes can teach us about the Employer of Last Resort

Australian unions are campaigning to “Change the Rules” to improve rights at work. A fundamental part of this should be a job guarantee, as advocated by political economist working within the Modern Monetary Theory frame. One of the outstanding workers in this field is Pavlina Tcherneva. This paper analysing what happened in Argentina after the collapse in 2001 is an indication of the impact the job guarantee has on local comunity, gender inequality, social power and community development.

She emphasises that the Argentinian program was not developed along the lines her c0-theorist were pushing but it did share many features.

Key aspects of the analysis did match Keynes arguments (so often ignored by what Joan Robinson referred to as “bastard Keynesianism) that it is not pump priming o the economy that works, rather that a DIRECT JOB CREATION program works.

Further it does not “destabilise”, it is countercyclical, it is sustainable in the long term in sovereign currency economies (like Argentina with Peso on floating exchange rather than tied to a fixed exchange rate with the US dollar, like Australia with its dollars, like US wit its dollars but NOT like Greece without its own currency.

It empowered women in particular (and this aspct was one of the standout features of the program that the male policy makers and community members were forced to recognise), it created and maintained socially useful work designed and controlled at the local level, but financed federally. Thus it was a way to advance greatly socio-economic goals by creating work that enhanced the community (and was not compulsory). The model was not based on the minimum wage so was not totally successful at bringing all out of poverty but did hve the immediate impact of lifting socio-economic development by creating jobs directly, rather than jobs growth happening AFTER growth begins, which is the mantra economists bash us with today.

This is hardly radical left wing revolutionary stuff but does create a workforce that is locally organised and in control of their work and life, just as unions would surely wish to be a part of.

 

 

Ceteris publicus

Pamphlets into the Wind on why unemployment is a policy creation not a natural phenomenon

But if we really want to run ceteris paribus into the ground, there’s one final comparison to make — the share of workers in the public sector. In 1966, almost one-quarter of employees found work with the government. It should be obvious where this is going. Let’s assume that, rather than paying people to be unemployed, the government started paying people to be employed. Maybe in constructing public housing, acting as teacher’s aides, providing home care support for the elderly, or improving transport like Paul Kelly did.

Enterprise Bargaining – Not just “Broken”, but Rotten to the Core

Don Sutherland on the whole trouble with our “Fair Work” Act and enterprise bargaining

Don Sutherland's Blog

Recently, I discussed Australia’s “broken” enterprise bargaining laws with Caroline Pryor on Radio Skid Row’s “Workers Radio”. Click here to listen. These “broken” laws are stacked against workers and are an essential element in driving more inequality in Australia.

Later that day, Australian Council of Trade Unions (ACTU) Secretary, Sally McManus, gave an important and revealing keynote address to the T.J. Ryan Foundation in Brisbane, Queensland. (Click here to read the released version.) McManus described increasing inequality in Australia and how the Fair Work Act 2009 (FWA09, the “rules”) is contributing to that. Also, she specifically talked about the enterprise bargaining rules that are stacked against workers.

In this post I include information not covered in the radio discussion, focus on just three of the broken enterprise bargaining rules, and discuss what the Australian Council of Trade Unions (ACTU) “Change the Rules” campaign should prioritize.

In Australia…

View original post 2,426 more words